Note: here is another dispatch from Fred Thompson.
Thanks to a series of initiatives and referenda during the
decade of the 1990s, primarily Measure 5, enacted in 1990, and Measure 50,
enacted in 1997, Oregon has acquired a one-off property-tax system, which
emphasizes stable growth in tax payments and inter-jurisdictional uniformity in
tax rates. The system seems to be somewhat popular. At least the property tax
no longer consistently tops the worst-tax list in local polls. Nevertheless,
the prestigious City Club of Portland, after a year spent studying property
taxes, concluded that “the current Frankentax has got to go” and proposed to
restore the property tax system that was in effect in 1990, with some major
modifications.
My reading of the evidence tells me that they are wrong, in
the sense that they want to take a sledgehammer to things where a tack hammer
would suffice. The current system gives Oregon a lot more funding
predictability and stability than the old one, it places different
jurisdictions on a more equal footing with respect to the provision of public
services, it has reduced the burden of property taxes across the board, and has
led to increased understanding on the part of voters about how much they will
pay and why; it has, as the City Club stresses, also greatly reduced local
autonomy, made public schools creatures of the state, reduced government
services, and reduced reliance on one of the most progressive tax sources
available (given that both wealth and income are measures of ability to pay).
Like the City Club, I too am troubled by the transfer
of fiscal autonomy from local school districts to the state. But, evidently,
that is precisely what the state’s taxpayers wanted. Insuring equal student
funding, while preserving local autonomy, is about as practicable as building a
perpetual motion machine. Much the same thing can be said about the regime’s effects
on the provision of general-government services. Here too, I share the City
Club’s concerns.
However, I would point out that the most severe local
service shortfalls, as in Curry and Josephine Counties, have occurred in
jurisdictions with statutory tax rates below one percent. State mandated
lock-in of general-government o tax rates was justified by compression-driven
cannibalization of inter-jurisdictional tax bases, but it applies equally to
all jurisdictions, whether they are in compression or not. That hardly makes
sense. Indeed, rather than freezing them, requiring the approval of any
affected jurisdiction to increase local rates would on the face of it
constitute a more reasonable fail-safe mechanism. If none of a jurisdiction’s
neighbors are affected by a tax increase or if arrangements satisfactory to all
the parties concerned can be worked out, the jurisdiction ought to be free to
raise rates consistent with the levies its citizens have authorized.
Moreover, we now have conclusive proof assessment
quality is slowly but inexorably deteriorating. That means that the burden of
the property tax is increasingly not borne in proportion to the value of
property owned, but is in fact arbitrarily and capriciously allocated. That is
unfair. It is also something that can and should be fixed.
With respect to this issue, the League of Oregon
Cities recently proposed a constitutional amendment that would “reset” a
property’s assessment for tax purposes to real market value when it is sold.
This looks like a reasonable solution to the problem of deteriorating
assessment quality. Reassessment to
market tends to improve tax uniformity. Moreover, from what we know
about residential mobility, the folks who are most likely to stay put are the
ones we want most to protect against rapid, unanticipated increases in their
tax bills: senior citizens without mortgages, perhaps the most important
beneficiaries of Measure 50. Shifting to a system of reassessment to market at
title transfer would preserve that protection. In any case, given the high
proportion of properties now at the Measure 5 limit and the general increase in
the assessment ratios that has taken place over the past five years, this seems
like a politically opportune time for political action. Right now reassessment
on title transfer would harm relatively few homeowners, primarily the ones who
have already received disproportionate gains under Measure 50.
How well
would this work? Probably reasonably well. Assessment quality is
deteriorating at the rate of about one percent each year; real estate turnover is
about eight percent. Consequently my guess is that reset at transfer would take
us to a stable coefficient of dispersion of less than 10 percent and covariance
levels between market value and tax payments of 90 percent or better.
2 comments:
I completely agree that the current property tax system--even from a municipality's perspective--is not that bad. Like other municipal finance officers, I whined about the declining changed-property ratios around 2006 and 2007 and how my city's tax revenues were taking a big hit. But after the financial crisis hit, I began to appreciate the shock absorber effect of Measure 50.
I don't doubt that some voter-approved reform is necessary. But while we're waiting for hell to freeze over, cities might want to consider revisiting their annexation, zoning, and development policies to make sure (1) that the land is bringing forth the maximum market value (and ultimately the maximum assessed value) that it can and (2) that investments in infrastructure yield a positive return.
Thanks, Doug. I appreciate your comment.
Post a Comment