Friday, February 25, 2011

Printing Money and Not Printing Money

Lately there has been a lot of fun made of Ben Bernanke about whether, as a per of QE2, the Fed is printing money.  "No," says Ben, we are simply marking up banks accounts.  Is this the same as printing money, well almost, but not exactly and herein lies a questions of semantics that Jim Hamilton takes on in the pages of Fortune Magazine:

But if the Fed didn't print any money as part of QE2 and earlier asset purchases, how did it pay for the stuff it bought? The answer is that the Fed simply credited the accounts that banks that are members of the Federal Reserve System hold with the Fed. These electronic credits, or reserve balances, are what has exploded since 2008. The blue area in the graph below is the total currency in circulation, whose growth we have just seen has been pretty modest. The maroon area represents reserves.


Are reserves the same thing as money? An individual bank is entitled to convert those accounts into currency whenever it likes. Reserves are also used to effect transfers between banks. For example, if a check written by a customer of Bank A is deposited in the account of a customer in Bank B, the check is often cleared by debiting Bank A's account with the Fed and crediting Bank B's account. During the day, ownership of the reserves is passing back and forth between banks as a result of a number of different kinds of interbank transactions.

To understand how the receipt of new reserves influences a bank's behavior, the place to start is to ask whether the bank is willing to hold the reserves overnight. Prior to 2008, a bank could earn no interest on reserves, and could get some extra revenue by investing any excess reserves, for example, by lending the reserves overnight to another bank on the federal funds market. In that system, most banks would be actively monitoring reserve inflows and outflows in order to maximize profits. The overall level of excess reserves at the end of each day was pretty small (a tiny sliver in the above diagram), since nobody wanted to be stuck with idle reserves at the end of the day. When the Fed created new reserves in that system, the result was a series of new interbank transactions that eventually ended in the reserves being withdrawn as currency.

All that changed dramatically in the fall of 2008, because (1) the Fed started paying interest on excess reserves, and (2) banks earned practically no interest on safe overnight loans. In the current system, new reserves that the Fed creates just sit there on banks' accounts with the Fed. None of these banks have the slightest desire to make cash withdrawals from these accounts, and the Fed has no intention whatever of trying to print the dollar bills associated with these huge balances in deposits with the Fed.

Of course, the situation is not going to stay this way indefinitely. As business conditions pick up, the Fed is going to have to do two things. First, the Fed will have to sell off some of the assets it has acquired with those reserves. The purchaser of the asset will pay the Fed by sending instructions to debit its account with the Fed, causing the reserves to disappear with the same kind of keystroke that brought them into existence in the first place. Second, the Fed will have to raise the interest rate it pays on reserves to give banks an incentive to hold funds on account with the Fed overnight.

Doing this obviously involves some potentially tricky details. The Fed will have to begin this contraction at a time when the unemployment rate is still very high. And the volumes involved and lack of experience with this situation suggest great caution is called for in timing and operational details. Sober observers can and do worry about how well the Fed will be able to pull this off.

But that worry is very different from the popular impression by some that hyperinflation is just around the corner as a necessary consequence of all the money that the Fed has supposedly printed.

[HT: Greg Mankiw]

1 comment:

Unknown said...

GDP is not as an important indicator of eocnomic health as many believe. GDP includes govenrment deficit spending and credit spending by the consumer, those two variables are most of what the GDP is comprised of. When you look at Debt to GDP you are in essence comparing Debt to Debt spending...so how can anybody seriously come to the conclusion that the indicator of a relative low Debt to GDP ratio is indicative of a healthy economy and a manageable debt load?....

Now, as far as future inflation is concerned. Let's face it, CPI does not reflect true inflation . As far as future inflation is concerned, it's totally pathetic to believe that the Federal Reserve with all the credit creation can tame massive inflation when it arrives. The Fed cannot do much to ensure that foreigners accept the USD as a means to settle international trade. Since the US is no long self-sustainable as a Nation from an Economic level it would cause massive inflation were the world to no longer accept the currency that the Fed loves to debase. The argument I just made is supported by the fact that many Nations and Empires that experienced hyperinflation as direct result of excessive money creation experienced most inflation on imported goods.

You can read more of my thoughts about business and economic news on my blog at WTF Finance .